How does a nation’s education system relate to its economic performance? Why do most workers with college degrees earn so much more than those without degrees? Understanding how education and training interact with the economy can help explain why some workers, businesses, and economies flourish, while others falter.
As the labor supply increases, downward pressure is placed on the wage rate. If employers’ demand for labor doesn’t keep up with the labor supply, wages usually fall.
An excess supply of workers is particularly harmful to employees working in industries with low barriers to entry for new employees—that is, those with jobs that don’t require a degree or any specialized training. Conversely, industries with higher education and training requirements tend to pay workers higher wages. The increased pay is due to a smaller labor supply capable of operating in those industries, and the required education and training carrying significant costs.
Key Takeaways
- The knowledge and skills of workers available in the labor supply are a key determinant for both business and economic growth.
- Industries with higher education and training requirements tend to pay workers higher wages.
- Differences in training levels is a significant factor that separates developed and developing countries.
- An economy’s productivity rises as the number of educated workers increases since skilled workers can perform tasks more efficiently.
How Education And Training Affect The Economy
How Education Benefits a Nation
Globalization and international trade require countries and their economies to compete with one another. Economically successful countries will hold competitive and comparative advantages over other economies, though a single country rarely specializes in a particular industry.
A typical developed economy will include various industries with different competitive advantages and disadvantages in the global marketplace. The education and training of a country’s workforce is a major factor in determining how well the country’s economy will perform.
How Job Training Influences the Economy
A successful economy has a workforce capable of operating industries at a level where it holds a competitive advantage over the economies of other countries. Nations may try incentivizing training through tax breaks, providing facilities to train workers, or a variety of other means designed to create a more skilled workforce. While it’s unlikely an economy will hold a competitive advantage in all industries, it can focus on a number of industries in which skilled professionals are more readily trained.
Differences in training levels are a significant factor that separates developed and developing countries. Although other factors are certainly in play, such as geography and available resources, having better-trained workers creates spillovers throughout the economy and positive externalities.
An externality can have a positive effect on an economy due to a well-trained workforce. In other words, all companies benefit from the external factor of having a skilled labor pool from which to hire employees. In some cases, the highly skilled labor force might be concentrated in a specific geographic region. As a result, similar businesses may cluster in the same geographic region because of those skilled workers—an example being Silicon Valley, Calif.
For Employers
Ideally, employers want workers who are productive and require less management. Employers must consider many factors when deciding whether or not to pay for employee training.
- Will the training program increase the productivity of the workers?
- Will the increase in productivity warrant the cost of paying for all or part of the training?
- If the employer pays for training, will the employee leave the company for a competitor after the training program is complete?
- Will the newly trained worker be able to command a higher wage?
- Will the worker gain an increase in bargaining power or leverage for a higher wage?
- If increases in pay are warranted as a result of the training, will the increases in productivity and profits be enough to cover any pay raises as well as the overall cost of the training program?
Many employers require workers to remain with the firm for a certain amount of time in exchange for paid training, eliminating the risk of newly trained workers leaving as soon as their free course ends.
Businesses may face employees who are unwilling to accept training. This can happen in industries dominated by unions since increased job security could make it more difficult to hire trained professionals or fire less-trained employees. However, unions may also negotiate with employers to ensure their members are better trained and thus more productive, which reduces the likelihood of jobs being shifted overseas.
For Workers
Workers increase their earning potential by developing and refining their capabilities and skills. The more they know about a particular job’s function and a particular industry, the more valuable they become to an employer.
Employees may want to learn advanced techniques or new skills in order to vie for a higher wage. Usually, workers can expect their wages to increase, but at a smaller percentage than the productivity gains by employers. The worker must consider a number of factors when deciding whether to enter a training program:
- How much extra productivity can they expect to gain?
- Is there a cost to the worker for the training program?
- Will the worker see a wage increase that would warrant the cost of the program?
- What are the labor market conditions for better-trained professionals in that field?
- Is the labor market significantly saturated with trained labor in that specialty?
Employers may pay for all or a portion of the training expenses, but this is not always the case. Also, a worker may lose income if the program is unpaid and they are unable to work as many hours as they had previously.
In some states, an employer may not be liable to cover the cost of work training. Employees must be paid for training time, though, unless the course takes place outside of normal working hours, is not related to the job, the employee doesn’t perform other work at the same time, and attendance is voluntary.
For the Economy
Many countries have placed greater emphasis on developing an education system that can produce workers able to function in new industries, such as science and technology. This is partly because older industries in developed economies have become less competitive, and thus are less likely to continue dominating the industrial landscape. Also, a movement to improve the basic education of the population has emerged, with a growing belief that all people have the right to an education.
When economists speak of “education,” the focus is not strictly on workers obtaining college degrees. Education is often broken into specific levels:
- Primary—elementary school in the U.S.
- Secondary—middle school, high school, and preparatory school
- Post-secondary—university, community college, vocational schools
A country’s economy becomes more productive as the proportion of educated workers increases since educated workers can more efficiently carry out tasks that require literacy and critical thinking. However, obtaining a higher level of education also carries a cost. A country doesn’t have to provide an extensive network of colleges or universities to benefit from education; it can provide basic literacy programs and still see economic improvements.
Countries with a greater portion of their population attending and graduating from schools see faster economic growth than countries with less-educated workers. As a result, many countries provide funding for primary and secondary education to improve economic performance. In this sense, education is an investment in human capital, similar to an investment in better equipment.
The ratio of the number of children of official secondary school age enrolled in school to the number of children of official secondary school age in the population (referred to as the enrollment ratio), is higher in developed nations than it is in developing ones.
The enrollment ratio differs as a metric from calculating education spending as a percentage of gross domestic product (GDP), which doesn’t always correlate strongly with the level of education in a country’s population. GDP represents the output of goods and services for a nation. Therefore, spending a high proportion of GDP on education doesn’t necessarily ensure that a country’s population is more educated.
For businesses, an employee’s intellectual ability can be treated as an asset. This asset can be used to create products and services that can be sold. The more well-trained workers employed by a firm, the more that firm can theoretically produce. An economy in which employers treat education as an asset is often referred to as a knowledge-based economy.
Like any decision, investing in education involves an opportunity cost for the worker. Hours spent in the classroom mean less time working and earning income. Employers, however, pay higher wages when the tasks required to complete a job require a higher level of education. In other words, although an employee’s income might be lower in the short-term to become educated, wages will likely be higher in the future once the training is complete.
Cobweb Model
The Cobweb Model helps to explain the effects of workers learning new skills. The model shows how wages fluctuate as workers learn a new skill, but also how the supply of workers is impacted over time.
The model shows that as workers learn a new skill, higher wages occur in the short run. However, as more workers get trained over time and enter the workforce to chase the higher wages, the supply of trained workers increases. Eventually, the result is lower wages due to an excess supply of workers. As wages fall, fewer workers are interested in those jobs, leading to a reduction in the supply of workers. The cycle begins again with training more workers and increasing their wages in the short run.
Since training and education take time to complete, shifts in the demand for particular types of employees have different effects in the long and short term. Economists demonstrate this shift using a cobweb model of labor supply and labor demand. In this model, the supply of labor is analyzed over the long term, but the shifts in demand and wages are viewed in the short term as they move toward a long-term equilibrium.
Figure 1: Short-term shifts in demand and wage rate
In the short run, the increase in demand for better-trained workers results in an increase in wages above the equilibrium level (graph A). We can see the shift in increased demand (D2) and where it intersects W2 representing the increased wages. However, L, which represents the short-term labor curve, also intersects W2 and D2.
Instead of the increase in wages being along the long-run labor supply curve (S), it’s along the more inelastic short-run labor supply curve (L). The short-run curve is more inelastic because there is a limited number of workers who have or are able to immediately train for the new skill set. As more and more workers are trained (graph B), the supply of labor shifts right (L2) and moves along the long-run labor supply curve (S).
Figure 2: New workers’ effect on wage rates
With the increase in the availability of new workers, there is downward pressure on the wage rate, which falls from W2 to W3 (graph C).
Figure 3: New wage equilibrium is established
Because of the falling wage rate, fewer workers are interested in training for the skills demanded by employers. As a result, wages rise (up to W4), although the increase in wages is coming in smaller and smaller increments. This cycle of wage increases and labor increases continues until it has reached equilibrium: the original upward shift in demand meets the long-run supply of labor (graph F).
Education, Training, and Race
In the U.S., education doesn’t always result in higher wages for all workers. According to the Economic Policy Institute, Black workers, for example, face significant and growing wage gaps, with Black men paid only 71 cents and Black women just 64 cents for every $1 White men earn.
These gaps are found at every job level, from low wage to high wage, but are highest in top-paid fields because of a lack of representation of Black workers in those professions. The gaps also persist across all levels of education: Black workers who have high school, college, and advanced degrees earn just 81.7%, 77.5%, and 82.4%, respectively, of what White workers with the same degree earn. And the unemployment rate of Black workers who have a bachelor’s degree is similar to that of White workers without a college education.
In the near future Black Americans will be more vulnerable to displacement because the jobs they tend to hold—such as truck drivers, food service workers, and office clerks—are more likely to be affected by the advent of automation. A 2019 McKinsey & Company report that examined these trends suggested that the outlook for African Americans can be improved by “shifting education profiles to align with growing sectors” and “engaging companies and public policy makers in developing reskilling programs.”
Without changes like these, as well as many others, the long-term, well-documented, and growing racial wealth gap that exists between whites and people of color threatens to constrain consumption, with an estimated cost to the U.S. economy of $1 trillion to $1.5 trillion between 2019 and 2028, or 4% to 6% of projected GDP in 2028.
Why Is Education Considered an Economic Good?
Education tends to raise productivity and creativity, and stimulate entrepreneurship and technological breakthroughs. All these factors lead to greater output and economic growth.
How Much More Do People with an Education Get Paid?
According to the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), in 2020, workers with professional or doctoral degrees had median weekly earnings of $1,893 and $1,885, respectively, followed by $1,545 for those with master’s degrees, $1,305 for bachelor’s degrees, and $938 for associate’s degrees. At the bottom of the list were workers without a high school diploma, with median weekly earnings of $619.
Who Foots the Bill for Mandatory Workplace Training?
Usually, if your employer requires you to attend a training program it will cover the cost of your course. Some states, such as California, make it a legal requirement for employers to cover all work-related expenses. Others, however, leave it up to the employer to decide.
If your employer is ordering you to pay for workplace training, check your local state
laws to determine if this is legal. If it is, read through your employment contract if you have one) and/or the company’s employee manual to see if there is any mention of mandatory training and the associated costs.
The Bottom Line
The knowledge and skills of workers available in the labor supply are key factors in determining both business and economic growth. Economies with a significant supply of skilled labor, brought on through formal education as well as vocational training, are often able to capitalize on this by developing more value-added industries, such as high-tech manufacturing.
Countries need to ensure through legislation and jobs programs that all their citizens have access to the education and training that can lift up workers, companies, and the entire economy.